DOCUMENT DE TREBALL XREAP2010-10 Like milk or wine: Does firm performance improve with age? Alex Coad (Max Planck Institute of Economics) Agustí Segarra (GRIT) Mercedes Teruel (GRIT) Like milk or wine: Does firm performance improve with age? Alex Coada, Agustí Segarrab and Mercedes Teruelb ABSTRACT: Our empirical literature review shows that little is known about how firm performance changes with age, presumably because of the paucity of data on firm age. For Spanish manufacturing firms, we analyse the firm performance related to firm age between 1998 and 2006. We find evidence that firms improve with age, because ageing firms are observed to have steadily increasing levels of productivity, higher profits, larger size, lower debt ratios, and higher equity ratios. Furthermore, older firms are better able to convert sales growth into subsequent growth of profits and productivity. On the other hand, we also found evidence that firm performance deteriorates with age. Older firms have lower expected growth rates of sales, profits and productivity, they have lower profitability levels (when other variables such as size are controlled for), and also that they appear to be less capable to convert employment growth into growth of sales, profits and productivity. Keywords: firm age, firm growth, LAD, financial structure, vector autoregression JEL CODES: L25, L20 Max Planck Institute of Economics, Evolutionary Economics Group, Kahlaische Strasse 10, D-07745 Jena, Germany Universitat Rovira i Virgili, Grup de Recerca d’Indústria i Territori, Avda. Universitat 1, 43204 Reus, Spain b a This paper has the financial support of the Ministry of Innovation and Science in the project ECO200908735 and the Catalan Government in the Consolidated Group of Research 2009-SGR-907. Furthermore, it has the support of the XREAP - Research in Applied Economics Network. We are grateful to Verònica Gombau for her research support. Any view expressed here and remaining errors are complete responsibility of the authors.   1 1. INTRODUCTION The literature often considers firm size and firm age as alternative measures of the same underlying phenomenon. Although they are closely related there are considerable differences among them. Based on an extensive Spanish dataset, this paper exploits these differences and analyses the relationship between firm performance and firm age for Spanish manufacturing firms with 3 or more employees between 1998 and 2006. This database is obtained from the Spanish business register and exhibits exhaustive information on firm age, performance and financial variables. This article contributes on the empirical literature by exploiting the fact that we have detailed information on firm age and firm performance. The previous literature does not present the evolution of performance variables over time, while we provide detail description over years. This is because many previous datasets do not contain data on firm age. We begin by analyzing the firm size distribution (measured in terms of log sales and log employees). Furthermore, we enrich the discussion introducing financial variables, productivity, profitability, employees and sales. We also look at growth rate autocorrelation and estimate a vector autoregression model of firm growth for different age groups. Our main results are the following. With reference to firm size distribution, as in previous works, it becomes less skewed as firms get older. The descriptive analysis also shows that young firms are smaller, less productive and less profitable, but in their early years they experience higher growth rates in terms of sales, productivity and profits. Also as firms get older, the weight of external financial sources steadily decreases while the equity ratio steadily becomes a more important financial source. The autocorrelation analysis shows its coefficients remain negative for older firms, suggesting that firm growth remains an erratic process even for experienced firms. Our vector autoregression results for different age groups suggest that young firms display a higher positive impact of employment growth on profits, sales and productivity, while older firms benefit more from sales growth. Finally, it appears a high sensitiveness of financial variables on firm growth which diminishes over time. Short-term debt also presents a higher impact than long-term on growth. Our results point out that firm performance differs across the life cycle and among firm characteristics. On the one hand, young firms show a high level of heterogeneity, in terms of firm size, performance and financial sources, but this diversity decreases over time. On the other hand, older firms show a moderate heterogeneity. The structure of the paper is as follows. The second section reviews the theoretical and empirical literature about firm performance and firm age. The third section describes the dataset. The fourth section shows details on the evolution of some key variables by age. The fifth section contains vector autoregression analysis of firm growth processes for different age groups. Finally, concluding remarks are reported.   2 2. LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1. Theoretical work It is not easy to find specific theoretical predictions for how firm age affects firm performance, because many theoretical models take firm size and firm age as representing the same fundamental concept. For example, Greiner (1972, p39) presents his ‘stages of growth’ model of organizational change in growing firms, in which size is linearly related to age. Other scholars have nonetheless made specific predictions about how firm performance changes with age. We summarize these theoretical predictions in terms of selection effects, learning-by-doing effects, and inertia effects. Selection effects Selection effects arise when selection pressures progressively eliminate the weakest firms, and result in an increase in the average productivity level of surviving firms, even if the productivity levels of individual firms do not change with age. This situation corresponds to the model in Jovanovic (1982), whereby firms are born with fixed productivity levels, and learn about their productivity levels as time passes. In Jovanovic’s influential model, low productivity firms are observed to exit, while high productivity firms remain in business. As a result, the average productivity of the cohort increases as the cohort ages, even if the productivity levels of individual firms remain constant over time. This can be written as follows:  N   d i  d  i 1 N   0,  dage dage d i 0 dagei Where πi corresponds to the productivity level of firm i, and N is the number of surviving firms. Learning-by-doing effects Learning by doing effects occur when firms increase their productivity as they learn about more productive production techniques and incorporate these improvements in their production routines (for an early contribution, see Arrow (1962), see also Vassilakis (2008) for a survey of the learning-by-doing concept). Learning by doing effects can be expected to be particularly relevant for young firms. Garnsey (1998, p541) writes that: “New firms are hampered by their need to make search processes a prelude to every new problem they encounter. As learning occurs, benefits can be obtained from the introduction of a repertoire of problem-solving procedures … eliminating open search from the problem-solving response greatly reduces the labour and time required to address recurrent problems.”   3 Furthermore, older firms may benefit from their greater business experience, established contacts with customers, and easier access to resources. This can be written as follows: d i 0 dagei For example, Sorensen and Stuart (2000) point out that entrepreneurs often lack detailed information about their jobs, firms and even the environments until they are active in the market. After a firm’s creation, an intense learning process starts and contributes to the firm’s growth and survival in the long-term. Also Chang et al. (2002) provide evidence on the existence of microeconomic “learning-by-doing” effects with positive effects on the aggregate output. Inertia effects As firms get older, they might become less productive if they become increasingly inert and inflexible. Barron et al. (1994) argue that old firms are prone to suffer from a ‘liability of obsolescence’ (because they do not fit in well to the changing business environment) and also a ‘liability of senescence’ (according to which they become ossified by accumulated rules, routines and organizational structures). These negative effects, which may be especially important for very old firms, can be denoted as follows: d i 0 dagei At a theoretical level Hannan and Freeman (1984) justify inertia effects as “an outcome of an ecological-evolutionary process”. The idea is that firms are not able to change as fast as their environments. Firms with inertia effects can survive applying strategies such as the creation of new firms designed specifically to take advantage of new opportunities. However, if firms are not able to adapt applying strategies, new entrants will enter in the industry. Accordingly, it is environmental changes, which favor some (inert) bundles of firm resources over others, that lead to differences in firm performance. Nevertheless, the three of these effects (i.e. selection, learning-by-doing and inertia) can be operating simultaneously on the industry. From a resource-based view, Helfat and Peteraf (2003) point out that in the market learning effects and inertia effects may coexist, suggesting that there exists a heterogeneity of capabilities and resources among firms. Those authors introduce the concept of the capability lifecycle in order to provide an explanation for the emergence and sustained heterogeneity of capabilities. Others such as Levinthal (1991) pointed out that firm learning contributes to organizational inertia and inertial forces, which are a prerequisite for intelligent adaptation.   4 2.2. Empirical work Early empirical work on firm dynamics looked at firm size but not firm age. The seminal work by Gibrat (1931) led to interest in the firm size distribution (e.g. Hart and Prais, 1956; Simon and Bonini, 1958) and also in the relationship between firm size and growth rate (e.g. Hall, 1987; Hart and Oulton, 1996).1 Later on, however, interest in firm age began to grow, as some studies included age as an explanatory variable in regressions that investigate differences in firm performance. A number of studies observed that age is usually negatively related to expected growth rate as well as growth rate variance.2 The relationship between firm age and survival has also been investigated by many researchers (see for example Evans, 1987a,b; Fariñas and Moreno, 2000; Mata and Portugal, 2004; Bartelsman et al., 2005), but the results have not been clear-cut. An early contribution coined the term `liability of newness' to describe how young organizations face higher risks of failure (Stinchcombe, 1965). More recently, however, authors have referred to the `liability of adolescence' (Bruderl and Schussler, 1990; Fichman and Levinthal, 1991) to explain why firms face an initial `honeymoon' period in which they are buffered from sudden exit by their initial stock of resources. Still others have identified liabilities of senescence and obsolescence (Barron et al., 1994) according to which older firms are expected to face higher exit hazards once other influences (such as firm size) are controlled for. More recently, researchers have begun to take more interest in the role age plays in the performance of surviving firms. Some authors have investigated age effects by focusing specifically on samples of young firms (Calvo, 2006; Garnsey et al., 2006; Stam and Wennberg, 2009). Some researchers have focused on the functional form of the aggregate age distribution, showing that the empirical density is well approximated by an exponential distribution (Coad, 2009b), while others have tracked the evolution of the FSD over time, for cohorts of ageing firms (Cabral and Mata, 2003; Angelini and Generale, 2008; Cirillo, 2010). Other research has focused on differences in performance and behaviour across firms of different ages. For instance, it has been suggested that the age of a firm is positively related to its productivity levels (Haltiwanger et al., 1999), a finding that we                                                              1 2 For a survey of the literature see Sutton (1997) and Coad (2009a). Research that has found a negative effect of age on firm growth includes Fizaine (1968) Evans (1987a, b), Dunne et al. (1989), Dunne and Hughes (1994), Fariñas and Moreno (2000), Correa et al. (2003) and Geroski and Gugler (2004) . While most studies find a negative effect of age on growth, a few have found a positive effect of age on growth (Das, 1995; Shanmugam and Bhaduri, 2002). Still others find an inverted U-shape relationship (Teruel-Carrizosa, 2010). Lotti et al. (2009) observe that while the growth of young firms displays a negative dependence on age, this becomes insignificant as time passes and the cohort of firms grows older. Moreno and Casillas (2007) observe that firm age does not help to discriminate between high-growth firms and moderate-growth firms in their sample of 7752 small Andalusian firms. A negative effect of age on growth rate variance has been found by Evans (1987a) and Dunne et al. (1989), among others.   5 verify in our data. Brown and Medoff (2003) investigate whether older firms pay higher wages. Bartelsman et al. (2005, p386) compare the post-entry growth rates of North American and European firms. Bellone et al. (2008) examine how pressures related to market selection (i.e. firm survival) change as firms age. Others have investigated how probability of innovation and productivity growth change across the firm age distribution (Huergo and Jaumandreu, 2004a,b). Autio et al. (2000) observe that young international firms – ‘born global’ firms – experience faster growth in international sales than their older counterparts. They interpret this finding as evidence that younger firms are better able to develop export capabilities because they are better able to learn how to succeed in uncertain environments. Attention has also been given to changes in financial structure in ageing firms. Fluck et al. (1997) found that external finance decreases as a proportion of total finance over the first 7-8 years of a firm’ life, while Berger and Udell (1998, p.620) show that a firm’s debt ratio decreases once small firms overpass their adolescence period (3-4 years old). Similarly, Reid (2003) tracks small businesses in their first few years after inception and observes that the debt ratio decreases over time. We complement this body of research on the financial structure of very young firms by describing how financial structure changes over a wider range of firm ages, for both young and also relatively old firms. This brief literature review has shown that, although progress has been made in our understanding of how firm age affects firm performance, there are still many opportunities remaining for improving our understanding of how firm behaviour changes as firms grow older. One reason, it seems, is the paucity of data on firm age in administrative datasets (and also for data coming from questionnaires). Headd and Kirchhoff (2009, p. 548) write that there is a “dearth of information by business age. Simply stated, industrial organization and small business researchers are deprived of firm-age data.” Some researchers have tackled these data limitations by using indirect measures of firm age.3 In this dataset of Spanish firms, however, age is directly reported for all firms. Thus, we complement the literature by investigating                                                              For example, Winker (1999) argues that firm size (measured as number of employees) can be used as a proxy for firm age. Bellone et al. (2008) do not have any direct data on firm age (their INSEE/EAE database does not contain any direct information on firm age), but age is calculated indirectly by considering the first time a firm is included in the national statistical office records – which essentially corresponds to the first time a firm passes the 20 employee threshold above which firms are required to send data to the national statistical office. Although there is only an imperfect correspondence between a firm's birth and the first time its employment exceeds 20 employees, this methodology can be justified because most manufacturing firms enter at a relatively large size (compared to service firms), and because their analysis centres on changes within ageing firms over time, rather than the performance of firms at specific ages. Another, related, approach used for calculating age is by measuring age relative to whether firms are present during the first year of the time period covered by the database (this approach is taken by e.g. Kandilov (2009), who takes firm age as a control variable). Yet another method for obtaining data on firms is by painstakingly collecting information on each individual firm one at a time (see e.g. Mishina et al 2004, p. 1188) – a methodology which is hardly feasible for large samples of small firms. 3   6 changes in firm growth and performance in separate subsamples of firms of different ages. 3. DATA This study uses the Spanish Mercantile Register through the System of Analysis of Iberian Balance Sheets (SABI database) compiled by Bureau van Dijk. This database offers exhaustive information over balance sheets and financial sources for an important number of firms. This sample contains 73,891 manufacturing firms in 2006 year that represents 51.29% from the total population firms in manufacturing sectors. Thus, a database like this is suitable for studying how firm performance varies with age. Our dataset is composed by manufacturing sectors belonging to the NACE classification with codes between 15 and 364 during the period 1998 to 2006.5 We restrict our analyses to firms with 3 or more employees, so the sample is limited to 62,259 firms that covers 61.72% of total Spanish manufacturing firms with 3 or more employees.6 This sample conforms to an unbalanced panel-data format. During the intermediate years of the period –between 2002 and 2004- the number of firms that enter in the Spanish Business Register increases. During these years increased the public monitoring to present the individual balance sheets in the Mercantile Register.7 The variables that we use for the empirical analysis are the following. Firm age is the difference between the current year and the year of firm creation according with the registration of the firm in the Mercantile Register. All firm performance variables (sales, value added, profits, equity, short-term and long-term debt) are deflated using sectoral Industrial Price Index of the Spanish National Institute of Statistics. Productivity is defined as value added divided by employees (i.e., labour productivity). Profitability is the ratio between accounting profits and sales, corresponding to the ‘Return on Sales’ ratio (following e.g. Bottazzi et al. 2008). Short-term debt ratio, Long-term debt ratio and Equity ratio are calculated as the ratios between those financial variables and total assets (following e.g. Sogorb-Mira, 2005).                                                              Here sectors 16 (tobacco) and 23 (petroleum) are not included given their sectoral specificities. Although there is information available for year 2007, it remains still incomplete and so we restrict our analysis until 2006. 6 We have data on smaller firms, but we choose the cut-off point at 3 employees because the data on smaller firms is particularly noisy. 7 Our database has difficulties to detect when a firm exits the market, given that they must report their exit to the Mercantile Register. In some cases exiting firms forget to give information in their exits, while continuing firms might ignore their obligation to send the information. Although this can be a small share of firms, tracking them is a difficult task. 5 4   7 Table 1: Descriptive variables Median and standard deviation in 2006 All 10 (99.07) 768.96 (44500.19) 270.07 (6772) 26.71 (90.04) 1.53 (67993.88) 297.87 (19370.84 ) 62.34 (7775.45) Less than 10 years 7 (57.73) 508.13 (19782.46) 179.31 (4396.40) 23.71 (138.05) 1.26 (112724.9) 217.09 (8726.03) 53.54 (8231.64) Between 10 and 19 10 (78.15) 723.59 (50359.21 ) 260.18 (5872.75) 26.22 (39.43) 1.66 (723.37) 272.28 (14785.15) 57.59 (5394.27) 20 or more years 19 (158.70) 1879.32 (58684.61) 631.05 (10152.02) 32.58 (46.89) 1.74 (209.27) 638.86 (32838.44) 96.88 (10022.65) Employees Sales Added Value Productivity Profitability FINANCIAL STRUCTURE Short-term debt Long-term debt % over total assets Short-term debt Long-term debt 51.39 (221.95) 10.45 (95.69) 0 (120.97) 6.93 (24230.72) 5.96 (575010.1 ) 3.83 (10093.04) 60.28 (351.76) 14.69 (151.39) 0 (154.59) 11.84 (41670.9 ) 10.54 (985298.70) 4.65 (17350.76) 50.05 (58.09) 10.45 (32.66) 0 (100.34) 5.78 (134.14) 4.90 (8055.37) 3.53 (342.42) 42.71 (105.82) 6.17 (39.74) 0 (96.21) 4.32 (324.17) 2.98 (777.11) 3.34 (783.38) GROWTH VARIABLES Employees Sales Added Value Productivity Source: own elaboration Table 1 shows the median and standard deviation in 2006 of main descriptive variables from our database. We classify firms into three roughly homogenous age groups.8 First, all the absolute variables increase with firm age group. In other words, when firms get older they are in general larger, their sales increase and their efficiency and profitability are also higher. Second, financial variables such as total amounts of short-term and long-term debt increase over time. Third, when we consider financial ratios defined in terms of debt/assets we find a negative relationship between firm age group and the ratio of external finance to assets. One possible explanation is that older firms are able to accumulate more internal financial resources and, thus, they are less dependent of external finance (which would be                                                              Here, we homogenize the groups according with the number of observations. However, previous empirical works distinguish different firm age classification. For instance, Berger and Udell (1998) classify firms in four periods: `Infant’ (0-2 years), `Adolescent’ (3-4 years), ´Middle-Aged’ (5-25 years) and ´Old´ (25 or more years). 8   8 consistent with the ‘Pecking Order Theory’ of financial structure (Myers and Majluf, 1984)). Long-term debt is related to the ability of firms to provide assurances about their assets. The related literature on corporate finance shows that young, small firms usually are less able to obtain internal funds. As a consequence, firms with greater difficulties have restricted access to credit often finance their investment projects with short-term finance, which is more expensive. Less informed investors may undervalue the firms’ project and, as a consequence, may ask for higher interest rates. In addition, the risk of failure is higher for small and young firms, and so banks may prefer lending on a short-term contract in order to gain control over the firm and its investment decisions, while long-term debt is more suited for firms that invest in projects that do not provide an immediate pay-off (Myers, 2001). Our results are partially consistent with this line of reasoning, because the short-term debt ratio decreases with age. However, we also observe that the long-term debt ratio decreases with age, which suggests that even the youngest firms in our sample can obtain access to long-term debt. Finally, regarding the growth variables, median growth rates decrease over the age groups regardless the variable. The only exception is employee growth which remains constant with a value equal to 0. Consequently, empirical data shows that the median young firm improves more in terms of efficiency and market share in comparison with the median old firm. Figure 1: the age distribution for the year 2006. Note the log scale on the y-axis. Kernel density fitted using an Epanenchnikov kernel (using gbutils 5.2).   Figure 1 presents the age distribution for firms in our sample. We observe that young firms are the most numerous, and that as age increases the number of firms steadily decreases. The data appear to be well approximated by a straight line of negative slope, which on our semi-log axes would indicate that firm age is approximately   9 exponentially distributed (more on this in Coad 2009b). The modal age of the age distribution for the year 2006 is 11 years, which suggests that young firms are underrepresented in our database. (Presumably, under-representation of very young firms can also help explain the peculiar age distributions found in Huergo and Jaumandreu (2004a, p198; 2004b, p558) and also Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006, p31).)9 We therefore draw the reader’s attention to the likely under-representation of very young firms in our data, which can be expected to have some implications on how our results should be interpreted. In particular, our data on very young firms may well be overrepresentative of larger firms with above-average performance. 4. ANALYSIS 4.1. Firm evolution We analyse first the evolution of the Firm Size Distribution according to employees and sales (Figure 2). In line with Cabral and Mata (2003), the FSD of employees for the whole sample (solid line) is skewed towards the right. Furthermore, Figure 2 sheds light on the relationship between the skewness and firm age. Specifically, the skewness of FSD of employees diminishes when considering older firms. To support the analysis of the distribution of employees, we add the FSD of sales over time. The figure shows that when considering cohorts of ageing firms, the skewness of the distribution of sales diminishes. Our results are in line with Cabral and Mata (2003), Angelini and Generale (2008) and Cirillo (2010).10 FSD of log Employees                     .4     FSD of log Sales (euros x1000)  .3 0 0 .1 .2 0 .1 .2 .3 0 2 4 More than 2 years logSize 6 8 More than 5 years More than 20 years More than 50 years 10 5 More than 2 years logSize 10 More than 5 years More than 20 years More than 50 years 15 More than 10 years More than 30 years More than 10 years More than 30 years Figure 2. Kernel density estimates for the firm size distribution (FSD) of Spanish manufacturing firms by age in 2006. The kernel density is estimated with an Epanenchnikov kernel bandwidth equal to 0.5.                                                              The database analysed in Huergo and Jaumandreu (2004a,b) has a modal age category from 5 to 8 years (if we ignore the residual 37+ age category), and the data in Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006) is apparently well approximated by a lognormal distribution, indicating that the mode is not the minimum observation. 9   10 Figures 3 and 4 present the growth rate distributions for employment growth rates and sales growth rates, for three age categories. In line with previous work (e.g. Bottazzi and Secchi, 2006), we observe that the growth rate distributions are ‘tentshaped’, indicating that most firms have growth rates close to zero while a nonnegligible proportion of firms experience rapid growth or decline. An interesting finding that is clearly visible in both of these plots is that while the left tail of the growth rate distribution seems roughly invariant to age, the right tail displays some dependence on age. These plots suggest that older firms are less likely to experience very fast growth rates (in terms of both employment and sales), although they have roughly the same chances as younger firms of facing accelerated decline. These growth rate distribution plots provide an interesting twist to the previous finding of a negative dependence of growth on age, by suggesting that age lowers the probability of firms experiencing fast growth while having little effect on the probability of firm decline. Our results are consistent with the quantile regression analysis in Reichstein et al. (2010) and Serrasqueiro et al. (2010), who observe that firm age has a significantly negative impact on growth for the positive-growth quantiles but a less significant effect on growth for the negative-growth quantiles of the growth rate distribution. Figure 3: growth rate distributions for employment growth rates, for different age categories. Note the log scale on the y-axis. Kernel density fitted using an Epanenchnikov kernel (using gbutils 5.2). Figure 4: growth rate distributions for sales growth rates, for different age categories. Note the log scale on the y axis. Kernel density fitted using an Epanenchnikov kernel (using gbutils 5.2). In order to deep into the analysis of the market selection mechanism along the firm life cycle, this section investigates the evolution of a number of key variables as firms age: (log) Sales, profitability, productivity, (log) profit levels, growth rates (of sales, productivity and profits); and also financial variables (Short-term debt, long-term debt and equity measured as a ratio over total assets). Our methodology of plotting the evolution of key variables by age builds on work by Fariñas and Moreno (2000, p259) and Huergo and Jaumandreu (2004a,b).                                                                                                                                                                                            However, Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006) report that they find no evidence for an evolution from a rightskewed to a log-normal size distribution. 10   11 Given that our database compiles information in all firm sizes, it is highly affected by the presence of extreme values. Although we restrict our analysis to firms with at least three employees, we still have many extreme observations. Thus, we show the median values for all variables because means are heavily influenced by outliers (especially for the financial ratio variables). We should comment also that we do not plot the median employment growth rate, because this is 0.00 in most cases corresponding to small firms that do not change their numbers of employees from one year to the next. With respect to the evolution of log Sales and profitability (measured as the ratio of profits over sales) we can see a positive evolution of the variables over time. Thus, young firms have less log sales and profitability in comparison with older firms that were active in the market in 2006. This positive evolution of the median values reflects two trends. 8 6 4 2 0 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 10 20 30 40 50 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 Firm age Firm age LnSales Profitability LnVaL LnProfits Figure 5. Evolution of log(Sales) and Profitability as firms’ age in 2006. Median values. Figure 6. Evolution of productivity levels and profit levels as firms age in 2006. Median values. First, the market pressures firms to increase their profitability and also their sales in order to survive. In line with Jovanovic (1982), efficient firms are more able to survive. In fact, these results are also confirmed by the evidence on the evolution of the log productivity and the log profits (Figure 6) given that those variables increase for each age. Second, Figures 5 and 6 show evidence on the firms’ capacity to grow over time. There appears an increase of the volume of productivity and profits when they are young, while their values stabilize around a value during some years. Figure 7 shows the evolution of growth of sales, productivity and profits according to firm age. Results confirm that young firms initially perform better than older firms. This evidence is in line with previous empirical regularities related to “age dependence”. One crucial variable affecting firm performance is access to financial markets. In that sense, Figure 7 shows the evolution of three financial variables in terms of ratios with respect to a firm’s total assets –the short-term debt ratio, the long-term debt ratio, and the equity ratio. In our dataset, short-term and long-term debt are negatively correlated with financial performance, indicating that resorting to debt finance is more   12 30 + years 30 + years common in badly-performing firms.11 With financial frictions probably young firms suffer from a higher need of external finance. On the one hand, our evidence shows that young firms present a median value of the short-term debt ratio that is higherthan for older firms. Also the long-term debt ratio presents a higher value during the first years. Generally speaking, external debt decreases its weight over time. On the other hand, the ratio of the equity over assets presents a positive trend over time. In other words, young firms have a lower ratio of own financial resources than older firms. Similar results have been previously obtained by Hall et al. (2000), and also Segarra et al. (2010) on a similar database for Catalan manufacturing firms12. 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 Firm age Growth of LnSales Growth of LnProfits Growth of LnVaL Figure 7. Evolution of growth of sales, growth of productivity, and growth of profits as firms age in 2006. The link between financial structure and firm size has been analysed exhaustively (Beck et al., 2005, 2006; Oliveira and Fortunato, 2006), but the analysis between financial structure and firm age are more scarce. However, recently some papers show that the key variable in the analysis of financial constraints is firm age. For instance, Binks and Ennew (1996) report that young firms are more financially constrained. However, financial structure is not independent of firm age. For young firms, the ability to obtain external finance is a key factor in their development, growth and survival. Aghion et al. (2007a) find that access to external finance has a particular impact on the entry of small firms, and that it improves market selection by allowing firms to be more competitive on a more equal footing. Additionally, financial accessibility significantly facilitates the post-entry growth of firms (Aghion et al., 2007b). Our results show that even the youngest firms in our database have access to long-term debt, and that the long-term debt ratio decreases with age, which suggests that the difficulties for young firms in obtaining long-term finance should not be exaggerated.                                                              The rank correlations between the short-term debt ratio and profitability, and long-term debt and profitability, respectively, are -0.2946 and -0.1135. 12 Their results show an inverse link between firm age and debt ratios but a positive relationship between firm age and debt absolute values. 11   30 + years 13 However, capital structure changes over firm age. Younger firms tend to use a wider variety of financial sources than their older counterparts. During a firm’s infancy period the availability to obtain internal equity tends to be extremely limited and younger firms report a relatively high debt finance ratio. As the firm establishes itself, however, it gains access to resources from its own productive activity - commercial borrowings, internal cash flow - and sources of external finance. Hence, over time firms tend to increase their internal equity ratio and decrease the level of debts sources13. 80 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 20 40 60 Firm age ST debt ratio Equity ratio LT debt ratio Figure 8. Evolution of financial variables as firms age – Long-term debt ratio, Short-term debt ratio, and Equity ratio in 2006. The firm’s ability to gain access to external financial sources and their needs to finance can be expected to vary with firm age. Young firms usually obtain less longterm bank debt and have limited equity capital in absolute values. Young firms depend basically on internal cash-flow and commercial debt. As the firm matures, equity capital and internal reserves acquire a more important role. Furthermore, internal cash-flow increases with firm age, in particular among those firms older than fifty years (Segarra and Teruel, 2009).14 We have observed that older firms are more productive and more profitable, and also that they are of a larger size. Are these older firms more productive because of their size, or is there a distinct age effect that can be detected while controlling for firm size? To investigate this potential age effect, we perform multivariate regressions for productivity, profitability, and equity ratio, including age as a independent variable,                                                              In general, these results are in line with Financial Corporate Theories (Hamilton and Fox, 1998). This evidence shows that firm age is critical. There is a monotonic improvement of the equity ratio as the firm age increases. There is strong evidence that at least some aspects of the financing patterns change over time. 14 For an extensive sample of Spanish manufacturing firms in the year 2006, for young firms (less than six years) equity capital represents just 6.9% of their total liabilities, while commercial borrowings account for up to 71.1%; and for older firms (with more than fifty years) their equity capital is equivalent to 27.3%; their short-term bank debt is equal to 36.5%, and their long-term bank debt is equal to 11.2% of total liability. Furthermore, internal cash flow increases with a firm’s age, in particular among those firms older than fifty years. 13   30 + years 14 and controlling for firm size (i.e. log(empl)i,t-1), short-term (STDR) and long-term debt ratios (LTDR), and also two-digit industry and year effects. Table 2: multivariate LAD regressions Productivity LnAge LnSize STDR LTDR Obs. R2 0.0530 (42.67) 0.1135 (116.28) -0.1551 (-88.97) -0.0338 (-47.69) 302621 0.1235 Profitability Equity ratio -0.1164 (-14.19) 0.2390 (37.06) -1.9734 (-171.26) -0.5341 (-114.02) 302206 0.0099 3.2366 (93.21) 1.3441 (49.23) -33.8239 (-694.75) -8.0998 (-408.49) 302584 0.1508 Note: t-statistics appear in brackets. These regression results (Table 2) show that there is a distinct age effect, operating independently of firm size. We observe that age has a positive effect on productivity, even after controlling for other influences. Interestingly enough, however, age has a negative effect on profitability. Although Figure 5 shows that profitability increases with age, when we control for other factors such as size, the effect of age becomes negative. While older firms are more profitable, on average, this is mainly because they are bigger. This is because their large size confers higher profitability levels, but the distinct effect of age is negative. Finally, the results in Table 2 show that age also has a large positive effect on the equity ratio. Here, we present evidence related to the firm performance and the financial sources. How does the theory link firm financial structure with age? Recently Berger and Udell (1998) developed a Financial Growth Cycle Model for small firms where the financial needs and financing options change as the size, age and information. When firms become older, more experienced, and more transparent, it likely will gain access to public equity or long-term debt financing.15 Berger and Udell’s (1998) model offers a complementary vision of the Pecking order theory, proposed by Myers (1984). Myers proposes that firms prefer to use internal sources of capital first and will use external sources only if internal sources are inadequate. Pecking order theory has been found to be particularly relevant in the small-business arena. Holmes and Kent (1991) found that small businesses experience a more intense version of pecking order in their                                                              Using an extensive sample with 22,842 firms for year 2003 from Spanish SABI database, SánchezVidal and Martín-Ugedo (2008) test the Berger and Udell’s (1998) model. Results show that firms tend to have different financing structures depending on age and size. The main results are: i) the hypothesis about equity is not confirmed, because older firms tend to have higher equity values, caused by the increasing reserves; ii) risk of the firm decrease with age. Also, López-Gracia and Aybar-Arias (2000) and Sánchez-Vidal and Martín-Ugedo (2005) empirically test the pecking order theory with samples of Spanish firms. 15   15 decisions because their access to appropriate external sources of capital is limited. While it has been noted that small businesses differ from larger firms in terms of capital structure decisions, their intense reliance on pecking order is only one of the variables that make small-business financing decisions unique. 4.2. Regression analysis for different ages We continue our investigation of how firm performance changes with age by plotting the evolution of some key regression coefficients relating to the dynamics of sales growth and profits growth (but not employment growth).16 The autocorrelation coefficients are obtained through use of the following equation: Gr_Salesit = α1 Gr_Salesi,t-1 + α2CTRLi,t-1 + εit Gr_Profitsit = β1 Gr_Profitsi,t-1 + β2 CTRLi,t-1 + εit (1) (2) Where Gr_Sales is the growth rate of sales, and Gr_Profits is the growth rate of profits (both are calculated by taking log-differences of size levels). We control for lagged log size measured on number of employees (LnSize) and, following SogorbMira (2005), also long-term and short-term financial ratios over assets (LTDR and STDR), and also include sets of dummy variables to control for specific years and two-digit industrial sectors. The regression equations are estimated using LAD (i.e. median regressions) that are less sensitive to outliers than OLS. This is especially important here, because previous work has shown that OLS and LAD give quite different estimates of autocorrelation coefficients for firm growth indicators (Bottazzi et al., 2010). We plot the evolution of the regression coefficients α1 and β1 in Figures 9 and 10. While the magnitudes of the autocorrelation coefficient profiles differ for sales growth and profits growth, the shape of the profiles across age classes is similar for these two growth variables. Very young firms have the most positive autocorrelation coefficients, suggesting that their previous performance will, on average, tend to repeat itself in the early years. However, this result contrasts with previous work emphasizing the prevalence of growth setbacks for young firms (Garnsey et al., 2006) and so we view our results for very young firms with a little caution.17                                                              We investigated the autocorrelation of employment growth, but since many (small) firms do not change the number of employees from one year to the next, the autocorrelation coefficients estimated by median regressions (LAD) are 0.0000 in many cases, which makes the results relatively uninteresting. 17 We already mentioned, in our comments on the aggregate age distribution in Figure 1, that very young firms might be underrepresented in our database (and also in other related empirical studies such as Huergo and Jaumandreu (2004a,b) and Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006)) if the true age distribution is supposed to be approximately exponential. If our dataset is biased towards including only those more successful young firms, then the autocorrelation coefficients might be biased upwards for very young firms, if those young firms that enjoy sustained success in their early years are overrepresented. We hope that future work will shed light on this issue. 16   16 .1 .05 0 -.05 -.1 -.15 30 + years -- Firm age 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 Firm age 20 22 24 26 28 30 L GlnSales Max CI Min CI L GlnProfits Max CI Min CI Figure 9: Autocorrelation coefficient for the growth of sales – i.e. α1 from equation (1), for firms of different ages. LAD coefficient estimate, with 95% error bars. Figure 10: Autocorrelation coefficient for the growth of profits – i.e. β1 from equation (2), for firms of different ages. LAD coefficient estimate, with 95% error bars. After a few years, however, the autocorrelation coefficient decreases, and stabilizes at this lower level, and does not change in any clear way as firms age. It is interesting that older firms, that have more experience, still experience negative growth rate autocorrelation, suggesting that their growth events are marked by an erratic ‘startand-stop’ dynamics as opposed to a smoother, more gradual growth. This negative autocorrelation in growth rates therefore seems to be a regular feature of the growth process, across a wide range of firms of all ages. We now investigate the evolution of some other key coefficients of firm behavior – how does firm growth respond to financial variables? We estimate the following regression equation, Gr_Salesit = γ1Gr_Profitsi,t-1 + γ2STDRi,t-1 + γ3LTDRi,t-1 + γ3CTRLi,t-1 + εit (3) Where Gr_Sales is the log growth of sales, Gr_Profits is the log growth of profits, and STDR and LTDR correspond to the short-term and long-term debt ratios, respectively. Our control variables here are lagged size, measured in terms of log(employees), and also year and two-digit industry dummies. We focus our attention on the coefficients γ1, γ2, and γ3, and we plot these coefficients in the following graphs (Figures 11, 12, and 13). .03 -.02 -.01 0 .01 .02 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 Firm age 20 22 24 26 28 30 LGrlnProfits Max CI Min CI       Figure 11: Sensitivity of firm growth to growth of profits – i.e.   γ1 from equation (3), for firms of different ages. LAD  coefficient estimate, with 95% error bars.   17 30 + years DD 32 30 + years 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 DD 32 -.3 -.25 -.2 -.15 -.1 -.05 DD 32 Figure 11 shows the evolution of the sensitivity of firm growth to the growth of profits – that is, the coefficient γ1 from equation (3).18 The growth of young firms is positively related to financial performance, which can be interpreted in terms of financial constraints and selection effects. Profitable young firms have higher expected growth rates than less profitable young firms. As age increases, however, firm growth becomes less dependent on financial performance (the coefficient is significantly negative in many cases) suggesting that selection pressures are less strong for older firms. .06 .04 .02 0 -.02 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 Firm age 20 22 24 26 28 30 30 + years DD 32 -.01 2 0 .01 .02 .03 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 Firm age 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 STDR Max CI Min CI LTDR Max CI Min CI Figure 12: Sensitivity of firm growth to the short‐   term debt ratio – i.e.  γ2 from equation (3), for  firms of different ages. LAD coefficient estimate,    with 95% error bars.   Figure 13: Sensitivity of firm growth to the long‐ term debt ratio – i.e.  γ3 from equation (3), for  firms of different ages. LAD coefficient estimate,  with 95% error bars.     Figures 12 and 13 show how sales growth depends on the short-term and long-term debt ratios, for firms of different ages. Similar patterns are displayed in both these figures, and we offer some speculative interpretation of these results. Young firms who have higher debt ratios (both short-term and long-term) experience faster growth, which is consistent with the hypothesis that those young firms who are able to obtain access to financial resources (as evidenced by their debt ratios) can use these resources to grow. The coefficients for older firms are also positive and significant (in most cases), but lower in magnitude. Firms that are indebted might be spurred on to higher growth in order to repay their debts promptly. Indebtedness might therefore put pressure on firms to improve their performance. Furthermore, indebtedness might also make firms pursue more risky strategies, that lead to both faster growth rates and also higher exit hazards. Although we do not investigate exit hazards here, we do observe that the debt ratio is associated with faster growth of sales.                                                              Replacing lagged profits growth with lagged profitability levels did not change the results in any substantial way. 18   18 5. VECTOR AUTOREGRESSIONS How does the growth process change for firms of different ages? In this section, we investigate the co-evolution of a number of growth rate variables in order to observe the interactions between these variables for firms of different ages. To this end, we apply a vector autoregression model of sales growth, employment growth, growth of profits and growth of productivity (following Coad (2010)) for different age groups. We begin by looking at the matrix of contemporaneous correlations for the main VAR series (Table 3): employment growth (Gr_Empl), productivity growth (Gr_LabProd), sales growth (Gr_Sales) and profits growth (Gr_Profits). These variables are correlated with each other, but the correlations are far from perfect. Particularly striking is the strong negative correlation between employment growth and labour productivity growth in our sample. Given that labour productivity growth is calculated as Value Added per employee, it appears that new employees are not able to make a proportionate contribution to Value Added, and so employment growth is associated with a reduction in labour productivity growth. Table 3: Contemporaneous correlations. Gr_Empl Gr_LabProd Gr_Sales Gr_Profits 1.000 Gr_Empl -0.694 1.000 Gr_LabProd 0.210 0.226 1.000 Gr_Sales 0.034 0.258 0.317 1.000 Gr_Profits Source: own elaboration. Moving on from this simple examination of contemporaneous correlations, we now turn to our vector autoregression estimation. Our regression equation is: wit = ζ1wi,t-1 + ζ 2wi,t-2 + CTRLi,t-1 + εit (4) where wit is an m×1 vector of random variables for firm i at time t. β corresponds to an m×m matrix of slope coefficients that are to be estimated. In this particular case, m=4 and corresponds to the vector [Employment growth (i,t), labour productivity growth (i,t), Sales growth (i,t), profits growth (i,t)]’. This regression equation is estimated by OLS and LAD, and although 2 lags of the VAR series are included in all of our VAR regressions, as well as control variables,19 we only report coefficients for the first lag in our results tables. Table 4 contains the regression results for the full sample, which are broadly in line with results from other databases.20 We observe negative correlation for each of the growth rate series, which is strongest for growth of labour productivity and growth of                                                              That is, we control for firm size (measured in terms of log(employees)), the ratio of short-term debt to total assets, and the ratio of long-term debt to total assets, year dummies, and two-digit industry dummies. 20 See Coad (2010) for an analysis of French data, Coad and Rao (2010) for US data, and Coad et al. (2008) for an analysis of Italian data. 19   19 profits. Among the other coefficients, the largest relationship is between lagged sales growth and subsequent growth of profits. An interesting feature of our dataset (which includes more small firms than in comparable studies) is that employment growth has a much smaller association with subsequent growth of sales and growth of profits. Table 4: OLS and LAD regressions. OLS regression L_Gr_Empl L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs Gr_Empl Gr_LabProd Gr_Sales Gr_Profits -0.3136 (-27.41) -0.0604 (-4.86) -0.0091 (-0.71) 0.0195 (1.12) 0.0215 (2.40) -0.4593 (-29.40) -0.0559 (-4.46) 0.0401 (2.24) 0.0239 (3.04) 0.0452 (4.85) -0.3122 (-22.24) 0.1955 (12.56) 0.0144 (11.63) 0.0185 (12.60) 0.0241 (14.70) -0.3904 (-76.90) 0.1488 120321 0.1581 120056 0.1075 120265 0.1285 106733 LAD regression L_Gr_Empl L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs Gr_Empl Gr_LabProd Gr_Sales Gr_Profits 0.0000 (0.00) -0.0325 (-10.33) 0.0617 (20.92) 0.0050 (0.47) 0.0000 (0.00) -0.2845 (-92.38) 0.0293 (10.14) 0.0123 (1.16) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0447 (16.04) -0.0733 (-27.98) 0.1583 (16.59) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0036 (5.35) -0.0022 (-3.49) -0.2820 (-117.90) 0.0000 120321 0.0386 120056 0.0094 120265 0.0374 106733 Note: t-statistics appear in brackets. OLS and LAD regression results are observed to differ in two important ways. First, the autocorrelation coefficients are much more strongly negative in the OLS case, as has been found in previous work (Bottazzi et al., 2010). This is presumably because OLS is more sensitive to extreme observations (‘outliers’). Second, the LAD coefficients for the employment growth equation are all equal to 0.0000, reflecting the fact that the median firm has an employment growth rate of exactly zero (due to indivisibilities in employment growth). Our main interest in these vector autoregressions of firm growth, however, concern changes in growth patterns for firms belonging to different age groups. Tables 5-6 contain the VAR results for three separate age groups. To begin with, we comment on the autocorrelation coefficients across age groups (Table 5). The autocorrelation coefficients do not show any clear pattern across age groups, although we can reject the hypothesis that autocorrelation coefficients become more positive as firms age. In other words, we can reject the hypothesis that firm growth is smoother and less erratic for older firms. Our results also suggest that employment growth plays a different role in firms of different ages. Younger firms are better able to convert employment growth into subsequent growth of sales, productivity and profits. Older firms, on the other hand,   20 are less successful at deriving growth of sales, productivity and profits from previous employment growth. Our results therefore suggest that employment growth is more appropriate in the case of young firms than for old firms. We speculate that this could be because young firms are more flexible, have a superior capacity to learn and adapt to new human resource configurations, and better able to internalize new employees into the workforce. Older firms may be too entrenched in existing routines to see how they can put new employees to their best use. Furthermore, our results suggest that sales growth undertaken by older firms is more profitable than for younger firms. For older firms, there are higher regression coefficients for the associations between sales growth, on the one hand, and growth of productivity and profitability, on the other. While younger firms may be better able to benefit from employment growth, older firms are better able to turn sales growth into higher profits and higher productivity levels. Several potential factors affecting firm growth are firm size and access to financial variables. For this reason, we examine the extent to which those variables affect the growth VAR equations. Table 6 reports the results for OLS and LAD estimations. As previously we have commented, our results for OLS are different from the LAD estimations due to the presence of extreme values. However, the sign of the coefficients are in essence similar to LAD. Our results show that firm growth is positively related to the financial variables reported by firms. One question that may arise is whether the change of the financial structure on the firm may have an effect on firm performance. Cabral and Mata (2003) have argued that financial constraints may be a factor of the evolution of the firm size distribution. Following empirical evidence on corporate finance (Petersen and Rajan, 1994; Berger and Udell, 1995), this result indicates the existence of financial constraints. In contrast, authors such as Angelini and Generale (2008) conclude that financial constraints are not very important in developed countries. Additionally, it is remarkable that short-term debt has a higher impact on firm growth compared with long-term debt. The higher sensitivity of the coefficient of the shortterm debt may be an indicator of higher financial constraints in the short term. Another question that deserves our attention is the firm size. Traditionally, the literature related to firm growth and financial access assumes that the according with firm size and firm age are similar, considering that small firms have a similar behavior to young firms. However, on average young firms are smaller than their counterparts, there exists a heterogeneity on the entrance decision. For that reason, it can be interesting to distinguish the effect of firm size on firm growth in the VAR regressions. In fact our results show an interesting pattern. For OLS estimations the impact of firm growth is negative on firm growth for employees, sales and profits, but positive for the growth of firm productivity. However, this pattern changes once we consider the LAD estimations for middle-aged firms and older firms. For those firms, the LAD shows a positive impact of firm size on firm growth.   21   Table 5: Vector autoregressions according with firm age group. OLS and LAD. Firm Age 1 L_Gr_Empl L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs L_Gr_Empl OLS Firm Age 2 L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs L_Gr_Empl 0.1525 36933 0.1707 36846 0.0762 36912 0.1261 32483 Firm Age 3 L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs Gr_Empl Gr_LabProd Gr_Sales Gr_Profits -0.2439 (-13.98) -0.0692 (-2.84) 0.0284 (0.02) 0.0395 (1.20) 0.0617 (4.07) -0.4649 (-14.46) -0.0387 (0.02) 0.0694 (1.89) 0.0408 (3.27) 0.0444 (2.67) -0.2627 (0.02) 0.2061 (7.68) 0.0147 (6.25) 0.0187 (6.48) 0.0234 (0.00) -0.3813 (0.01) -0.3314 (-18.65) -0.0654 (-4.03) -0.0305 (-1.60) 0.0168 (0.66) -0.0003 (-0.02) -0.4487 (-23.65) -0.0710 (-3.75) 0.0187 (0.73) 0.0337 (0.01) 0.0397 (3.42) -0.3176 (-15.48) 0.1864 (7.86) 0.0115 0.1435 52491 (0.00) 0.0173 0.151 52382 (8.47) 0.0219 0.1068 52467 (0.00) -0.4022 0.1375 46667 (-52.52) -0.4138 (-15.39) -0.0686 (-2.60) -0.0709 (-2.63) -0.0518 (-1.43) 0.0005 -0.0223 (0.04) (-1.30) -0.4901 0.0498 (-16.45) (2.32) -0.0597 -0.4068 (-2.58) (-13.67) 0.0178 0.1919 (0.56) (6.03) 0.0155 0.2046 30897 (7.18) 0.021 0.168 30828 (7.28) 0.0256 0.1955 30886 (8.56) -0.3851 0.1201 27583 (0.01) Firm Age 1 L_Gr_Empl L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs L_Gr_Empl LAD regressions Firm Age 2 L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs L_Gr_Empl Firm Age 3 L_Gr_LabProd L_Gr_Sales L_Gr_Profits R2 obs 0.0000 52491 0.0397 52382 0.0100 5246 Gr_Empl Gr_LabProd Gr_Sales Gr_Profits -0.0056 (-8.95) -0.0169 (-2.77) 0.0814 (14.56) 0.0509 (2.64) 0.014 (22.41) -0.2793 (-45.43) 0.0431 (7.66) 0.0475 (2.40) 0.0095 (17.53) 0.0267 (5.01) -0.0676 (-13.84) 0.1387 (8.26) 0.0002 0.0001 36933 (1.75) 0.0026 0.044 36846 (1.88) -0.0005 0.0093 36912 (-0.39) -0.2677 0.0362 32483 (-58.40) 0.0000 (0.00) -0.0417 (-8.00) 0.0552 (11.51) -0.0064 (-0.36) 0.0000 (0.00) -0.2903 (-57.26) 0.027 (5.80) -0.0055 (-0.32) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0489 (10.67) -0.0912 (-21.53) 0.1547 (9.97) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0033 (3.16) -0.0044 (-4.61) -0.2939 (-78.70) 0.0414 46667 0.0000 (0.00) -0.0738 (-12.83) 0.0223 (4.33) -0.0706 (-3.12) 0.0000 0.0000 (0.00) (0.00) -0.2984 0.073 (-56.36) (14.35) 0.0128 -0.0798 (2.71) (-17.54) -0.0272 0.1838 (-1.31) (9.19) 0.0000 0.0000 30897 (0.00) 0.0048 0.0339 30828 (4.29) -0.0005 0.0111 30886 (-0.50) -0.2765 0.035 27583 (-59.39) Note: t-statistics appear in brackets.       22    Table 6: Vector autoregressions according with firm age group. Financial variables and firm size OLS Firm Age 1 Firm Age 2 Ln Size LTDR STDR R2 obs Ln Size LTDR STDR R2 obs Ln Size Firm Age 3 LTDR STDR R2 obs Gr_Empl Gr_LabProd Gr_Sales Gr_Profits -0.0808 (-33.06) 0.0479 (19.85) -0.0205 (-8.81) -0.0207 (-3.52) 0.0080 (5.42) 0.0141 (8.76) 0.0194 (11.91) 0.0399 (9.51) 0.0151 (3.80) 0.0308 (6.18) 0.0279 (5.98) 0.1681 (14.65) 0.1525 36933 0.1707 36846 0.0762 36912 0.1261 32483 -0.0450 (-25.40) 0.0331 (18.31) -0.0019 (-1.12) -0.0162 (-3.62) 0.0050 (5.11) 0.0113 (9.96) 0.0140 (12.07) 0.0187 (6.49) 0.0205 0.1435 (7.80) 0.0278 0.151 (9.33) 0.0398 0.1068 (12.35) 0.1243 0.1375 (15.58) 52491 52382 52467 46667 -0.0165 (-9.93) 0.0120 (6.48) 0.0052 (2.97) -0.0087 (-1.68) 0.0040 (4.23) 0.0082 (6.69) 0.0094 (7.47) 0.0040 (1.17) 0.0221 0.2046 30897 (6.59) 0.0256 0.168 30828 (6.65) 0.0374 0.1955 30886 (8.91) 0.1054 0.1201 27583 (10.33) Firm Age 1 Ln Size LTDR STDR R2 obs Ln Size LAD regressions Firm Age 2 LTDR STDR R2 obs Ln Size Firm Age 3 LTDR STDR R2 obs Gr_Empl Gr_LabProd Gr_Sales Gr_Profits -0.0017 (-11.62) 0.0199 (13.62) -0.0050 (-3.76) -0.0038 (-0.84) 0.0003 (2.51) 0.0090 (8.42) 0.0084 (8.61) 0.0284 (8.63) 0.0005 0.0001 36933 (1.94) 0.0318 0.044 36846 (11.57) 0.0174 0.0093 36912 (6.91) 0.1161 0.0362 32483 (13.57) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0122 (12.00) 0.0027 (2.90) 0.0009 (0.27) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0068 (9.93) 0.0061 (9.77) 0.0134 (5.84) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0228 (12.91) 0.0184 (11.39) 0.0885 (14.92) 0.0000 0.0397 0.0100 0.0414 52491 52382 5246 46667 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0012 (1.24) 0.0035 (4.17) 0.0024 (0.66) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0051 (8.04) 0.0031 (5.57) 0.0024 (1.00) 0.0000 (0.00) 0.0169 (9.00) 0.0130 (7.72) 0.0631 (8.62) 0.0000 30897 0.0339 30828 0.0111 30886 0.0350 27583 Note: t-statistics appear in brackets.   23  6. CONCLUSIONS As firms grow older, they experience many changes and transformations: from vitality to stability, from flexibility to rigidity, from learning capacity to exploitation of routines, from institutional opacity and uncertainty to an established organization. In this empirical analysis, we sought to provide new evidence on the effects of age on firm performance and behaviour. We begin our conclusion by reconsidering our cheesy title – do firms deteriorate with age (like milk) or do they improve with age (like wine)? In this paper we found evidence supporting both the milk hypothesis and the wine hypothesis. As evidence that firms improve with age, we found that ageing firms experience rising levels of productivity, profits, larger size, lower debt ratios, and higher equity ratios. Furthermore, older firms are better able to convert sales growth into subsequent growth of profits and productivity. On the other hand, we also found evidence that firm performance deteriorates with age. Older firms have lower expected growth rates of sales, profits and productivity, they have lower profitability levels (when other variables are controlled for), and also that they appear to be less capable to convert employment growth into growth of sales, profits and productivity. Analysis of the growth rate distributions for different age groups shows that older firms are less likely to experience fast growth, while they are just as likely as younger firms to experience rapid decline. Theoretical work has frequently suggested that young firms are particularly vulnerable to selection pressures. In our sample, firms have higher expected growth rates in their first few years. As they grow older, they grow not only in terms of sales and employees, but also in terms of productivity and profitability. Young firms have higher levels of short and long term debt (and a lower equity ratio) but as they age their ratio of debt decreases and their equity ratio increases. We observed that autocorrelation coefficients are negative over most of the age distribution, and that autocorrelation coefficients show no clear tendency of becoming more positive with age. This suggests that growth projects undertaken by older firms are no smoother and no less erratic than the growth of their younger counterparts. Put differently, it would appear that the negative autocorrelation often observed in the growth rates of small firms is an inherent feature of the growth process that cannot be explained in terms of the lack of experience of small young firms. Interestingly enough, the results of our vector autoregressions suggest that younger firms are more successful at converting employment growth into growth of sales, profits, and productivity. Meanwhile, older firms seem to do better at converting sales growth into growth of profits and productivity. As such, we speculate that employment growth is more appropriate during youth, while a focus on sales growth appears to be more appropriate during maturity. Another interesting question concerns how initial conditions (e.g. initial size) affect firm performance many years later. Presumably there is a relationship between start  24 up conditions and subsequent performance. Although we have shown that firm age is an important variable, initial conditions and start-up size can be expected to have long-lasting effects on firm. It would be interesting to investigate this in further work, using an appropriately selected subsample of our database. REFERENCES Agarwal, R. and Gort, M. (1996). The Evolution of Markets and Entry, Exit and the Survival of Firms. Review of Economics and Statististics 78 (3), 489-98 Aghion, P., Angeletos, G., Banerjee, A., and Manova, K. (2007a). Volatility and Growth: Credit Constraints and Productivity-Enhancing Investment. Unpublished manuscript. Aghion, P., Fally, T. and Scarpetta, S. (2007b). Credit constraints as a barrier to the entry and postentry growth of firms. Economic Policy 22(52), 731-790. Angelini, P. and Generale, A. (2008). On the evolution of firm size distributions. American Economic Review 98(1), 426-438. Arrow, K.J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies 29, 155–73. Autio, E., Sapienza, H.J. and Almeida, J.G. (2000). Effects of age at entry, knowledge intensity, and imitability on international growth. Academy of Management Journal 43(5), 909-924 Barron, D. N., West, E. and Hannan, M. T. (1994). A time to growth and a time to die: Growth and mortality of credit unions in New York, 1914-1990. American Journal of Sociology 100(2), 381421. Bartelsman, E., Scarpetta, S. and Schivardi. F. (2005). Comparative analysis of firm demographics and survival: evidence from micro-level sources in OECD countries. Industrial and Corporate Change 3, 365–391. Beck, T., Degirgüc-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (2005). Financial and Legal Constraints to Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?. The Journal of Finance 60(1), 137-177. Bellone, F., Musso, P., Nesta, L. and Quere, M. (2008). Market selection along the firm life cycle. Industrial and Corporate Change 17(4), 753-777. Berger, A.N. and Udell, G.F. (1995). Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance. Journal of Business 68, 351–381. Berger, A.N. and Udell, G.F. (2005). The Economics of Small Business Finance: The Roles of Private Equity and Debt Markets in the Financial Growth Cycle. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=137991 or doi:10.2139/ssrn.137991 Berger, N.A. and Udell, F. G. (1998). The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal of Banking & Finance 22(6-8), 613673. Binks, M.R. and Ennew, C.T. (1996). Growing firms and the credit constraint. Small Business Economics 8(1), 17-25. Bottazzi, G. and Secchi, A. (2006). Explaining the distribution of firms growth rates. Rand Journal of Economics 37, 234–263. Bottazzi, G., Coad, A., Jacoby, N. and Secchi, A. (2010). Corporate growth and industrial dynamics: Evidence from French manufacturing. Applied Economics (Forthcoming: doi: 10.1080/00036840802400454). Bottazzi, G., Secchi, A. and Tamagni, F. (2008). Productivity, profitability and financial performance. Industrial and Corporate Change 17(4), 711-751. Brock, W. A. and Evans, D. S. (1986). The Economics of Small Businesses (Holmes and Meier, New York). Brown, C. and Medoff, J.L. (2003). Firm age and wages. Journal of Labor Economics, 23:3, 677-697 Bruderl, J. and Schussler, R. (1990). Organizational Mortality: The Liabilities of Newness and Adolescence. Administrative Science Quarterly 35(3), 530-547. Cabral, L. M. B. and Mata, J. (2003). On the evolution of the firm size distribution: Facts and theory. American Economic Review 93(4), 1075-1090. Calvo, J. L. (2006). Testing Gibrat's law for small, young and innovating firms. Small Business Economics 26, 117-123. Caves, R. E. (1998). Industrial Organization and New Findings on the Turnover and Mobility of Firms”, Journal of Economic Literature 36(4), 1947-1982. Chang, Y., Gomes, J.F. and Schorfheide, F. (2002). Learning-by-Doing as a Propagation Mechanism. American Economic Review 92(5), 1498-1520.   25 Cirillo, P. (2010). An analysis of the size distribution of Italian firms by age. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 389: 459-466. Coad, A., Rao, R. and Tamagni, F. (2008). Growth Processes of Italian Manufacturing Firms. LEM Papers Series 2008/20, Laboratory of Economics and Management (LEM), Sant'Anna School of Advanced Studies, Pisa, Italy. Coad, A. (2009a). The Growth of Firms: a Survey of Theories and Empirical Evidence. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Coad, A. (2009b). Investigating the exponential age distribution of firms. Papers on Economics and Evolution 2009-23, Max Planck Institute of Economics, Evolutionary Economics Group. Coad, A. (2010). Exploring the processes of firm growth: evidence from a vector auto-regression. Industrial and Corporate Change, forthcoming. DOI: 10.1093/icc/dtq018 Coad A, Rao R (2010). Firm Growth and R&D expenditure. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 19 (2), 127-145.Correa, A., Acosta, M., González, A. and Medina, U. (2003). Size, Age and Activity Sector on the Growth of the Small and Medium Firm Size. Small Business Economics 21(3), 289-307. Das, S. (1995). Size, age and firm growth in an infant industry: The computer hardware industry in India. International Journal of Industrial Organization 13(1), 111–126. Dunne, P. and Hughes, A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s. Journal of Industrial Economics 42(2), 115–40. Dunne, T., Roberts, M. and Samuelson, L. (1989). The growth and failure of US manufacturing plants. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(4), 671–98. Ericson, R. and Pakes, A. (1995). Markov- Perfect Industry Dynamics: A Framework for Empirical Work. Review of Economic Studies 62(1), 53-82. Evans, D. S. (1987a). The relationship between firm growth, size and age: Estimates for 100 manufacturing industries. Journal of Industrial Economics 35, 567-581. Evans, D. S. (1987b). Tests of alternative theories of firm growth. Journal of Political Economy 95(4), 657-674. Fagiolo, G. and Luzzi, A. (2006). Do liquidity constraints matter in explaining firm size and growth? Some evidence from the Italian manufacturing industry. Industrial and Corporate Change 15(1), 139. Fariñas, J. and Moreno, L. (2000).Firms’ Growth, Size and Age: A Nonparametric Approach. Review of Industrial Organization 17, 249–265. Fariñas, J. C. and Martín, A. (2001). Tamaño empresarial, flexibilidad de costes y cambio tecnológico. Papeles de Economía Española 89-90, 272-285. Fichman, M. and Levinthal, D. (1991). Honeymoons and the liability of adolescence: A new perspective on duration dependence in social and organizational relationships. Academy of Management Review 16(2), 442-468. Fizaine, F. (1968). Analyse statistique de la croissance des entreprises selon l'age et la taille. Revue d'economie politique 78, 606-620. Fluck, Z, Holtz-Eakin, D. and Rosen, H. (1997). Where Does the Money Come From? An Empirical Investigation of Small Entrepreneurial Enterprises”, Syracuse University. Metropolitan Studies Program Series Occasional Paper No. 191. Garnsey, E. (1998). A Theory of the Early Growth of the Firm. Industrial and Corporate Change 7 (3), 523-556. Garnsey, E., Stam, E. and Heffernan, P. (2006). New firm growth: Exploring processes and paths. Industry and Innovation 13(1), 1-20. Geroski, P. A. and Gugler, K. (2004). Corporate growth convergence in Europe. Oxford Economic Papers 56, 597-620. Gibrat, R. (1931). Les inegalites economiques: applications, aux inegalites des richesses, a la concentration des entreprises, aux populations des villes, aux statistiques des familles, etc.: d'une loi nouvelle la loi de l'effet proportionnel. Recueil Sirey, Paris. Greiner, L. (1972). Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, 37-46. Hall, B. H. (1987). The relationship between firm size and firm growth in the US manufacturing sector. Journal of Industrial Economics 35(4):583-600. Hall, G., Hutchinson, P. and Michaelas, N. (2000). Industry effects on the determinants of unquoted SMEs capital structure. International Journal of the Economics of Business 7 (3), 297-312. Haltiwanger, J., Lane, J. and Spletzer, J. (1999). Productivity differences across employers: The roles of employer size, age, and human capital. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 89(2), 94-98. Hamilton, R.T. and Fox, M.A. (1998). The financing preferences of small firm owners. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour & Research 4 (3), 239-248.   26 Hannan, M.T. and Freeman, J. (1984). Structural Inertia and Organizational Change. American Sociological Review 49(2), 149-164. Hart, P. and Prais, S. (1956). The analysis of business concentration: A statistical approach. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 119(2), 150-91. Hart, P. E. and Oulton, N. (1996). The growth and size of firms. Economic Journal 106(3), 1242-1252. Headd, B. and Kirchhoff, B. (2009). The Growth, Decline and Survival of Small Businesses: An Exploratory Study of Life Cycles. Journal of Small Business Management 47(4), 531-550. Helfat, C.E. and M.A. Peteraf (2003). The Dynamic resource-based view: capability lifecycles. Strategic Management 24, 977-1010. Holmes, S. and Kent, P. (1991). An empirical analysis of the financial structure of small and large Australian manufacturing enterprises. The Journal of Small Business Finance 1(2), 141-154. Huergo, E. and Jaumandreu, J. (2004a). How does probability of innovation change with firm age? Small Business Economics 22(3), 193-207. Huergo, E. and Jaumandreu, J. (2004b). Firms' age, process innovation and productivity growth. International Journal of Industrial Organization 22(4), 541-559. Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica 50(3), 649-670. Kandilov, I. T. (2009). Do exporters pay higher wages? plant-level evidence from an export refund policy in Chile. World Bank Economic Review 23(2), 269-294. Levinthal, D.A. (1991). Organizational Adaptation and Environmental Selection – Interrelated Processes of Change. Organization Science 2(1), 140-145. López-Gracia, J. and Aybar-Arias, C. (2000). An empirical approach to the financial behaviour of small and medium sized companies. Small Business Economics 14, 55-63. Lotti, F., Santarelli, E. and Vivarelli, M. (2009). Defending Gibrat's Law as a long-run regularity. Small Business Economics 32, 31-44 Mata, J. and Portugal,P. (2004). Patterns of Entry, Post-Entry Growth and Survival: A Comparison Between Domestic and Foreign Owned Firms. Small Business Economics 22(3-4): 283-298. Mishina, Y., Pollock, T.G., and Porac, J.F. (2004). Are more resources always better for growth? Resource stickiness in market and product expansion. Strategic Management Journal 25, 11791197. Moreno, A. and J. Casillas (2007). High-growth SMEs versus non-high growth SMEs: a discriminant analysis. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 19, 69–88. Myers, S.C. (1984). The capital structure puzzle, Journal of Finance 39, 575–592. Myers, S.C. (2001). Capital structure. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15, 81–102. Myers, S.C. and Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187–22. Oliveira, B. and A. Fortunato (2006). Firm growth and liquidity constraints: a dynamic analysis. Small Business Economics 27, 139–156. Petersen, M.A. and Rajan, R.G. (1994). The benefits of lending relationships: evidence from small business data. Journal of Finance 49, 3–37. Reichstein T, Dahl, M.S., Ebersberger, B. and Jensen, M.B. (2010). The devil dwells in the tails: A quantile regression approach to firm growth. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 20, 219–231. Reid, G.C. (2003). Trajectories of small business financial structure. Small Business Economics 20, 273-285. Sánchez-Vidal, J. and Martín-Ugedo, J.F. (2005). Financing Preferences of Spanish Firms: Evidence on the Pecking Order Theory. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 25 (4), 341-355. Sánchez-Vidal, J. and Martín-Ugedo, J.F. (2008).Edad y tamaño empresarial y ciclo de vida financiero. IVIE, WP-EC 2008-12. Segarra A, Teruel, M., Vidal, A. and Alarcón, S. (2010). Creixement i restriccions financeres a les empreses Industrials de Catalunya, Catalan Government, Departament of Economics. Forthcoming. Segarra, A. and Teruel, M. (2009). Small firms: the effects of financial constraints on their growth. XREAP, WP XREAP2009-11. Serrasqueiro, Z., Nunes, P.M., Leitao, J. and Armada, M. (2010). Are there non-linearities between SME growth and its determinants? A quantile approach. Industrial and Corporate Change, forthcoming. Shanmugam, K. and Bhaduri, S. (2002). Size, age and firm growth in the Indian manufacturing sector. Applied Economics Letters 9(9), 607–613. Simon, H. and Bonini, C. (1958). The size distribution of business firms. American Economic Review 48(4), 607-617. Sogorb-Mira, F. (2005). How SME uniqueness affects capital structure: evidence from a 1994-1998 Spanish data panel. Small Business Economics 25, 447-457.   27 Sorensen J. and Stuart, T. (2000). Aging, obsolescence and organisational innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 45(1), 81-112. Stam, E. and Wennberg, K. (2009). The roles of R&D in new firm growth. Small Business Economics 33(1), 77-89. Stinchcombe, A. (1965). Social structure and organizations. In March, J. G., editor, Handbook of Organizations, pages 142-193. Rand McNally, Chicago. Sutton, J. (1997). Gibrat’s Legacy. Journal of Economic Literature 35(1), 40-59. Teruel-Carrizosa, M. (2010). Gibrat's law and the learning process. Small Business Economics, Forthcoming. DOI 10.1007/s11187-008-9127-9 Vassilakis, S. (2008) Learning-by-doing. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan, Winker, P. (1999). Causes and effects of financing constraints at the firm level. Small Business Economics 12(2), 169-181.     28 SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP 2006 CREAP2006-01 Matas, A. (GEAP); Raymond, J.Ll. (GEAP) "Economic development and changes in car ownership patterns" (Juny 2006) CREAP2006-02 Trillas, F. (IEB); Montolio, D. (IEB); Duch, N. (IEB) "Productive efficiency and regulatory reform: The case of Vehicle Inspection Services" (Setembre 2006) CREAP2006-03 Bel, G. (PPRE-IREA); Fageda, X. (PPRE-IREA) "Factors explaining local privatization: A meta-regression analysis" (Octubre 2006) CREAP2006-04 Fernàndez-Villadangos, L. (PPRE-IREA) "Are two-part tariffs efficient when consumers plan ahead?: An empirical study" (Octubre 2006) CREAP2006-05 Artís, M. (AQR-IREA); Ramos, R. (AQR-IREA); Suriñach, J. (AQR-IREA) "Job losses, outsourcing and relocation: Empirical evidence using microdata" (Octubre 2006) CREAP2006-06 Alcañiz, M. (RISC-IREA); Costa, A.; Guillén, M. (RISC-IREA); Luna, C.; Rovira, C. "Calculation of the variance in surveys of the economic climate” (Novembre 2006) CREAP2006-07 Albalate, D. (PPRE-IREA) "Lowering blood alcohol content levels to save lives: The European Experience” (Desembre 2006) CREAP2006-08 Garrido, A. (IEB); Arqué, P. (IEB) “The choice of banking firm: Are the interest rate a significant criteria?” (Desembre 2006) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP CREAP2006-09 Segarra, A. (GRIT); Teruel-Carrizosa, M. (GRIT) "Productivity growth and competition in spanish manufacturing firms: What has happened in recent years?” (Desembre 2006) CREAP2006-10 Andonova, V.; Díaz-Serrano, Luis. (CREB) "Political institutions and the development of telecommunications” (Desembre 2006) CREAP2006-11 Raymond, J.L.(GEAP); Roig, J.L.. (GEAP) "Capital humano: un análisis comparativo Catalunya-España” (Desembre 2006) CREAP2006-12 Rodríguez, M.(CREB); Stoyanova, A. (CREB) "Changes in the demand for private medical insurance following a shift in tax incentives” (Desembre 2006) CREAP2006-13 Royuela, V. (AQR-IREA); Lambiri, D.; Biagi, B. "Economía urbana y calidad de vida. Una revisión del estado del conocimiento en España” (Desembre 2006) CREAP2006-14 Camarero, M.; Carrion-i-Silvestre, J.LL. (AQR-IREA).;Tamarit, C. "New evidence of the real interest rate parity for OECD countries using panel unit root tests with breaks” (Desembre 2006) CREAP2006-15 Karanassou, M.; Sala, H. (GEAP).;Snower , D. J. "The macroeconomics of the labor market: Three fundamental views” (Desembre 2006) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP 2007 XREAP2007-01 Castany, L (AQR-IREA); López-Bazo, E. (AQR-IREA).;Moreno , R. (AQR-IREA) "Decomposing differences in total factor productivity across firm size” (Març 2007) XREAP2007-02 Raymond, J. Ll. (GEAP); Roig, J. Ll. (GEAP) “Una propuesta de evaluación de las externalidades de capital humano en la empresa" (Abril 2007) XREAP2007-03 Durán, J. M. (IEB); Esteller, A. (IEB) “An empirical analysis of wealth taxation: Equity vs. Tax compliance” (Juny 2007) XREAP2007-04 Matas, A. (GEAP); Raymond, J.Ll. (GEAP) “Cross-section data, disequilibrium situations and estimated coefficients: evidence from car ownership demand” (Juny 2007) XREAP2007-05 Jofre-Montseny, J. (IEB); Solé-Ollé, A. (IEB) “Tax differentials and agglomeration economies in intraregional firm location” (Juny 2007) XREAP2007-06 Álvarez-Albelo, C. (CREB); Hernández-Martín, R. “Explaining high economic growth in small tourism countries with a dynamic general equilibrium model” (Juliol 2007) XREAP2007-07 Duch, N. (IEB); Montolio, D. (IEB); Mediavilla, M. “Evaluating the impact of public subsidies on a firm’s performance: a quasi-experimental approach” (Juliol 2007) XREAP2007-08 Segarra-Blasco, A. (GRIT) “Innovation sources and productivity: a quantile regression analysis” (Octubre 2007) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP XREAP2007-09 Albalate, D. (PPRE-IREA) “Shifting death to their Alternatives: The case of Toll Motorways” (Octubre 2007) XREAP2007-10 Segarra-Blasco, A. (GRIT); Garcia-Quevedo, J. (IEB); Teruel-Carrizosa, M. (GRIT) “Barriers to innovation and public policy in catalonia” (Novembre 2007) XREAP2007-11 Bel, G. (PPRE-IREA); Foote, J. “Comparison of recent toll road concession transactions in the United States and France” (Novembre 2007) XREAP2007-12 Segarra-Blasco, A. (GRIT); “Innovation, R&D spillovers and productivity: the role of knowledge-intensive services” (Novembre 2007) XREAP2007-13 Bermúdez Morata, Ll. (RFA-IREA); Guillén Estany, M. (RFA-IREA), Solé Auró, A. (RFA-IREA) “Impacto de la inmigración sobre la esperanza de vida en salud y en discapacidad de la población española” (Novembre 2007) XREAP2007-14 Calaeys, P. (AQR-IREA); Ramos, R. (AQR-IREA), Suriñach, J. (AQR-IREA) “Fiscal sustainability across government tiers” (Desembre 2007) XREAP2007-15 Sánchez Hugalbe, A. (IEB) “Influencia de la inmigración en la elección escolar” (Desembre 2007) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP 2008 XREAP2008-01 Durán Weitkamp, C. (GRIT); Martín Bofarull, M. (GRIT) ; Pablo Martí, F. “Economic effects of road accessibility in the Pyrenees: User perspective” (Gener 2008) XREAP2008-02 Díaz-Serrano, L.; Stoyanova, A. P. (CREB) “The Causal Relationship between Individual’s Choice Behavior and Self-Reported Satisfaction: the Case of Residential Mobility in the EU” (Març 2008) XREAP2008-03 Matas, A. (GEAP); Raymond, J. L. (GEAP); Roig, J. L. (GEAP) “Car ownership and access to jobs in Spain” (Abril 2008) XREAP2008-04 Bel, G. (PPRE-IREA) ; Fageda, X. (PPRE-IREA) “Privatization and competition in the delivery of local services: An empirical examination of the dual market hypothesis” (Abril 2008) XREAP2008-05 Matas, A. (GEAP); Raymond, J. L. (GEAP); Roig, J. L. (GEAP) “Job accessibility and employment probability” (Maig 2008) XREAP2008-06 Basher, S. A.; Carrión, J. Ll. (AQR-IREA) Deconstructing Shocks and Persistence in OECD Real Exchange Rates (Juny 2008) XREAP2008-07 Sanromá, E. (IEB); Ramos, R. (AQR-IREA); Simón, H. Portabilidad del capital humano y asimilación de los inmigrantes. Evidencia para España (Juliol 2008) XREAP2008-08 Basher, S. A.; Carrión, J. Ll. (AQR-IREA) Price level convergence, purchasing power parity and multiple structural breaks: An application to US cities (Juliol 2008) XREAP2008-09 Bermúdez, Ll. (RFA-IREA) A priori ratemaking using bivariate poisson regression models (Juliol 2008) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP XREAP2008-10 Solé-Ollé, A. (IEB), Hortas Rico, M. (IEB) Does urban sprawl increase the costs of providing local public services? Evidence from Spanish municipalities (Novembre 2008) XREAP2008-11 Teruel-Carrizosa, M. (GRIT), Segarra-Blasco, A. (GRIT) Immigration and Firm Growth: Evidence from Spanish cities (Novembre 2008) XREAP2008-12 Duch-Brown, N. (IEB), García-Quevedo, J. (IEB), Montolio, D. (IEB) Assessing the assignation of public subsidies: Do the experts choose the most efficient R&D projects? (Novembre 2008) XREAP2008-13 Bilotkach, V., Fageda, X. (PPRE-IREA), Flores-Fillol, R. Scheduled service versus personal transportation: the role of distance (Desembre 2008) XREAP2008-14 Albalate, D. (PPRE-IREA), Gel, G. (PPRE-IREA) Tourism and urban transport: Holding demand pressure under supply constraints (Desembre 2008) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP 2009 XREAP2009-01 Calonge, S. (CREB); Tejada, O. “A theoretical and practical study on linear reforms of dual taxes” (Febrer 2009) XREAP2009-02 Albalate, D. (PPRE-IREA); Fernández-Villadangos, L. (PPRE-IREA) “Exploring Determinants of Urban Motorcycle Accident Severity: The Case of Barcelona” (Març 2009) XREAP2009-03 Borrell, J. R. (PPRE-IREA); Fernández-Villadangos, L. (PPRE-IREA) “Assessing excess profits from different entry regulations” (Abril 2009) XREAP2009-04 Sanromá, E. (IEB); Ramos, R. (AQR-IREA), Simon, H. “Los salarios de los inmigrantes en el mercado de trabajo español. ¿Importa el origen del capital humano?” (Abril 2009) XREAP2009-05 Jiménez, J. L.; Perdiguero, J. (PPRE-IREA) “(No)competition in the Spanish retailing gasoline market: a variance filter approach” (Maig 2009) XREAP2009-06 Álvarez-Albelo,C. D. (CREB), Manresa, A. (CREB), Pigem-Vigo, M. (CREB) “International trade as the sole engine of growth for an economy” (Juny 2009) XREAP2009-07 Callejón, M. (PPRE-IREA), Ortún V, M. “The Black Box of Business Dynamics” (Setembre 2009) XREAP2009-08 Lucena, A. (CREB) “The antecedents and innovation consequences of organizational search: empirical evidence for Spain” (Octubre 2009) XREAP2009-09 Domènech Campmajó, L. (PPRE-IREA) “Competition between TV Platforms” (Octubre 2009) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP XREAP2009-10 Solé-Auró, A. (RFA-IREA),Guillén, M. (RFA-IREA), Crimmins, E. M. “Health care utilization among immigrants and native-born populations in 11 European countries. Results from the Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe” (Octubre 2009) XREAP2009-11 Segarra, A. (GRIT), Teruel, M. (GRIT) “Small firms, growth and financial constraints” (Octubre 2009) XREAP2009-12 Matas, A. (GEAP), Raymond, J.Ll. (GEAP), Ruiz, A. (GEAP) “Traffic forecasts under uncertainty and capacity constraints” (Novembre 2009) XREAP2009-13 Sole-Ollé, A. (IEB) “Inter-regional redistribution through infrastructure investment: tactical or programmatic?” (Novembre 2009) XREAP2009-14 Del Barrio-Castro, T., García-Quevedo, J. (IEB) “The determinants of university patenting: Do incentives matter?” (Novembre 2009) XREAP2009-15 Ramos, R. (AQR-IREA), Suriñach, J. (AQR-IREA), Artís, M. (AQR-IREA) “Human capital spillovers, productivity and regional convergence in Spain” (Novembre 2009) XREAP2009-16 Álvarez-Albelo, C. D. (CREB), Hernández-Martín, R. “The commons and anti-commons problems in the tourism economy” (Desembre 2009) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP 2010 XREAP2010-01 García-López, M. A. (GEAP) “The Accessibility City. When Transport Infrastructure Matters in Urban Spatial Structure” (Febrer 2010) XREAP2010-02 García-Quevedo, J. (IEB), Mas-Verdú, F. (IEB), Polo-Otero, J. (IEB) “Which firms want PhDs? The effect of the university-industry relationship on the PhD labour market” (Març 2010) XREAP2010-03 Pitt, D., Guillén, M. (RFA-IREA) “An introduction to parametric and non-parametric models for bivariate positive insurance claim severity distributions” (Març 2010) XREAP2010-04 Bermúdez, Ll. (RFA-IREA), Karlis, D. “Modelling dependence in a ratemaking procedure with multivariate Poisson regression models” (Abril 2010) XREAP2010-05 Di Paolo, A. (IEB) “Parental education and family characteristics: educational opportunities across cohorts in Italy and Spain” (Maig 2010) XREAP2010-06 Simón, H. (IEB), Ramos, R. (AQR-IREA), Sanromá, E. (IEB) “Movilidad ocupacional de los inmigrantes en una economía de bajas cualificaciones. El caso de España” (Juny 2010) XREAP2010-07 Di Paolo, A. (GEAP & IEB), Raymond, J. Ll. (GEAP & IEB) “Language knowledge and earnings in Catalonia” (Juliol 2010) XREAP2010-08 Bolancé, C. (RFA-IREA), Alemany, R. (RFA-IREA), Guillén, M. (RFA-IREA) “Prediction of the economic cost of individual long-term care in the Spanish population” (Setembre 2010) XREAP2010-09 Di Paolo, A. (GEAP & IEB) “Knowledge of catalan, public/private sector choice and earnings: Evidence from a double sample selection model” (Setembre 2010) SÈRIE DE DOCUMENTS DE TREBALL DE LA XREAP XREAP2010-10 Coad, A., Segarra, A. (GRIT), Teruel, M. (GRIT) “Like milk or wine: Does firm performance improve with age?” (Setembre 2010) xreap@pcb.ub.es